hacia un índice del costo de vida

download hacia un índice del costo de vida

of 15

Transcript of hacia un índice del costo de vida

  • 7/29/2019 hacia un ndice del costo de vida

    1/15

    Toward a Cost-of-Living Index:Progress and Prospects

    Katharine G. Abraham

    Almost anyone with an interest in consumer price trends wants to know how

    those trends affect consumers, and, in principle, that effect is best captured by

    an appropriate cost-of-living index. It therefore seems curious that so few of

    the statistical offices around the world have adopted the cost-of-living index objective

    for their consumer price indexes. Accurately tracking the cost of purchasing a fixed

    market basket of goods and services no doubt offers a more comfortable standard for

    a statistical agency to aspire to than accurately tracking the cost of living. But if thelatter is what one really would like to measure, it seems better just to say so.

    For some years, the theory of the cost-of-living index has guided Bureau of

    Labor Statistics (BLS) decisions about the Consumer Price Index (CPI), and in the

    recent past, the agency has stated more explicitly that the goal for the CPI program

    is to approximate a conditional cost-of-living indexthat is, an index that mea-

    sures changes in the cost of living that are due to changes in prices of goods and

    services, conditional on other outside influences that affect the standard of living

    remaining unchanged. It may be that a true cost-of-living index is unattainable as

    a practical matter. Still, the Consumer Price Index surely can be moved closer to

    that ultimate objective, and the theory of the cost-of-living index has the consider-able advantage of offering a unified framework for the evaluation of the methods

    used to produce the CPI.1

    1 Triplett (2001) provides a nice discussion of issues related to adoption of the cost-of-living index as the

    conceptual framework for a consumer price index. For some different perspectives, see Hill (1999) and

    Turvey (1999). Greenlees (2001) discusses how the Bureau Labor Statistics has used the cost-of-living

    index framework to guide its decisions about the Consumer Price Index.

    yKatharine G. Abraham is Professor, Joint Program in Survey Methodology, University of Maryland, College Park, Maryland. From 1993 to 2001, she served as Commissioner, Bureau

    of Labor Statistics, U.S. Department of Labor, Washington, D.C.

    Journal of Economic PerspectivesVolume 17, Number 1Winter 2003Pages 4558

  • 7/29/2019 hacia un ndice del costo de vida

    2/15

    In this paper, I consider the improvements the Bureau of Labor Statistics has

    made to the Consumer Price Index since the mid-1990s. These include changes

    designed to make the index more representative of current expenditure patterns;

    to account for consumer substitution in response to relative price change; andto account for changes in the quality of the goods and services that con-

    sumers purchase. Drawing on selected recommendations made by the National

    Academy of Sciences Panel on Conceptual, Measurement, and Other Statistical

    Issues in Developing Cost-of-Living Indexes recently chaired by Charles Schultze

    (hereafter, the Schultze panel), I highlight those additional areas for exploration

    that I believe have the greatest potential and discuss those areas I believe to be less

    promising.

    A Primer on the Consumer Price Index

    The Bureau of Labor Statistics describes the CPI on its website at http://

    www.bls.gov/cpi/cpifaq.htm as a measure of the average change over time in the

    prices paid by urban consumers for a market basket of consumer goods and ser-

    vices. Construction of the Consumer Price Index begins with the selection of the

    individual items to be priced. Prices are collected in each of 87 geographic areas for

    items in each of 186 item categories or strata.2 All of the nations 31 largest metropol-

    itan areas are included in the survey sample; another 56 areas are selected to represent

    the remainder of the countrys urban population. The item categories are designedto be as homogeneous as possible while still covering everything a consumer might

    purchase for current consumption. There are, for example, separate item strata for

    breakfast cereal; garbage and trash collection; bedroom furniture; household paper

    products; womens dresses; dental services; and college tuition and fees. Subindexes

    for each of the area/item strata cells form the building blocks for the aggregate CPI.

    The selection of specific items for pricing is designed to ensure that the items

    priced are representative of what consumers actually purchase. First, for each

    geographic area, the outlets contacted by the Consumer Price Index data collectors

    are selected randomly, with a probability of selection proportional to the outlets

    share of sales in an item category based on the Point of Purchase Survey (POPS),which collects information on where consumers shop. The outlets selected may

    include on-line vendors or catalog retailers in addition to bricks-and-mortar stores

    and offices. Once the outlet sample has been picked, the specific items to be priced

    also are selected randomly, again with a probability of selection proportional to

    sales, as closely as that can be determined.3 Each item chosen for inclusion in the

    2 There are another 25 strata for which no prices are collected. Price change in these strata, whichaccount for less than 1 percent of total consumer spending, is imputed from the movements in priced

    strata.3 It is perhaps worth noting that no other country in the world uses a fully probabilistic process like thatemployed in the United States to select the items to be priced in the Consumer Price Index. The typical

    46 Journal of Economic Perspectives

  • 7/29/2019 hacia un ndice del costo de vida

    3/15

    CPI sample receives a weight that reflects, at least approximately, the aggregate

    volume of base period sales it represents, and that weight is used in the calculation

    of the relevant area/item stratum subindex. Prior to 1999, the change in a subindex

    between the base period and the current period was calculated for all strata as theweighted arithmetic mean of the change in included items prices; as will be

    described shortly, a different formula now is used in a majority of strata.

    Once the subindexes have been computed, they must be aggregated to form

    the overall CPI. This is done using a set of expenditure share weights that represent

    the purchases of a typical consumer. The expenditure data used to form these weights

    are taken from the Consumer Expenditure Survey, an ongoing survey that collects

    detailed information on the spending patterns of a representative sample of house-

    holds. The change in the overall index between the base period and the current

    period equals the weighted arithmetic mean of the changes in the component indexes.

    Faster Rotation of Items into the Consumer Price Index

    Historically, the sample of outlets at which prices were collected for the Con-

    sumer Price Index and the specific items priced in those outlets were updated on a

    five-year schedule, so that each year the full sample of priced items was replaced in

    20 percent of the urban areas covered by the Consumer Price Index. Beginning

    in 1998, the Point of Purchase Survey (POPS) has been converted from an in-person

    to a telephone survey, and the Bureau of Labor Statistics has shortened the timeframe for the scheduled rotation of all priced items from five years to four years.

    Because drawing a new outlet sample and making first visits to begin data

    collection in those outlets is labor intensive, further shortening the period over

    which a full item sample rotation occurs would be very expensive. It is technically

    possible to target selected item categories for more rapid sample rotation, but as

    Lane (2001) explains, this would have to be done very selectively indeed. At

    present, the BLS has the resources to carry out a full rotation of a quarter of the CPI

    outlet and item sample each year. If one were to rotate 25 percent of the CPI

    sample every two years rather than every four years, it would be possible to rotate

    the remaining 75 percent of the price quotations only once every six years.Largely because of cost and resource considerations, the BLS has begun to

    develop alternative approaches. New outlets and new items for the prescription drug

    stratum were selected in February 2000. During 2002, a new set of prescription drugs

    practice in other countries is to collect prices for a list of speci fic items designated by the statisticalagencys headquarters office to represent the different categories of consumer expenditure. In Canada,for example, prices are collected for something over 600 speci fic items, and the set of outlets in whichprice data are collected is determined judgmentally based on regional managers knowledge of which

    outlets have the largest sales volume. Although there is no evidence that this process generatessystematic bias in the Canadian CPI, there is also no real guarantee that the set of items selected forpricing is representative of what consumers actually purchase.

    Katharine G. Abraham 47

  • 7/29/2019 hacia un ndice del costo de vida

    4/15

    was selected for pricing at the existing set of prescription drug outlets. A standard

    sample rotation is scheduled for the prescription drug stratum in 2004, with an

    item-only updating again following in 2006, and so on. In other words, even though the

    outlets will be rotated at the same pace as previously (on a four-year cycle), the itemswill be rotated more rapidly (on a two-year cycle). The Bureau of Labor Statistics

    received new funding in 2002 to support the sort of interim item-only sample updating

    first attempted for prescription drugs across many of the commodities and services

    tracked to produce the CPI. Where implemented, this change will effectively reduce

    the planned sample life of any specific item from four years to two years. To the extent

    that changes in consumer purchasing patterns are reflected in sales at particular

    outlets, rather than only in shifts of sales across outlets, this change should go a great

    distance toward ensuring the currency of the item sample.

    In addition, other more narrowly targeted efforts have been made to ensurethe currency of the sample in particular item categories where rapid change is

    recognized to be the norm. For example, since 1995, whenever a generic equivalent

    for a prescription drug priced in the index becomes available, the generic drug has

    been given the opportunity to replace brand name price quotes using a probabi-

    listic process that should yield a share for the generic roughly equivalent to its

    market share six months after introduction. Since 2000, new personal computer

    samples have been selected in existing outlets once every six months.

    One important question about bringing new items into the CPI sample is

    whether and how their prices will be compared to those of the items they replace.

    In each of the examples just cited, a different approach has been adopted. At leastfor now, when a two-year interim updating of the item sample is carried out at the

    existing sample of outlets, the prices of the new items will not be directly compared

    to the prices of the items they replace. Not comparing the new and old items prices

    in essence attributes the entire price difference to a difference in the items quality.

    In the generic drug case, the full difference in price between the branded and the

    generic drug is captured as a price decline, thereby effectively treating the branded

    and the generic drug as equivalent in quality. In the personal computer case, the

    price differences between the new computers and those they replace are adjusted

    based on hedonic models designed to capture the value of the quality differences

    between the new and old machines, with any remaining price difference treated asa true price change. Identifying the best approach to handling these comparisons

    is an important part of the ongoing effort at the BLS to improve the treatment of

    quality change in the CPI, a subject I will take up shortly.

    Keeping the Expenditure Weights Current

    Prior to 1998, the Consumer Expenditure Survey weights used in aggregating

    the CPI subindexes to form the overall CPI were updated only about once every tenyears. The weights were based on three years of survey data. Because of lags in the

    collection and processing of those data, the weights were 312 years old when first

    48 Journal of Economic Perspectives

  • 7/29/2019 hacia un ndice del costo de vida

    5/15

    introduced. By the time the weights were replaced a decade or so later, they

    obviously were much older.

    Effective in January 2002, the Bureau of Labor Statistics has shifted to updating

    the expenditure share weights every two years. A 50 percent expansion of theConsumer Expenditure Survey sample from roughly 5,000 to roughly 7,500 house-

    holds that took effect in 1999 allows the weights to be calculated based on two years,

    rather than three years, of data. Moreover, the processing of the expenditure data

    has been accelerated. Together, these changes mean that the CPI expenditure

    share weights are now two years old (rather than 312 years old) at the time of their

    introduction and will be four years old (rather than 13 to 15 years old) at the time

    they are replaced. For example, the expenditure share weights introduced in

    January 2002 used information from 1999 and 2000. In January 2004, they will be

    replaced with newer weights based on 20012002 data.The age of the weights has a less straightforward relationship to the rate of

    growth in the Consumer Price Index than might have been expected. The BLS

    announcement that future weight updates would occur on a two-year cycle, avail-

    able at http://www.bls.gov/cpi/cpiupdt.htm , notes that implementation of this

    policy following the 1987 revision of the CPI would have slowed the rate of growth

    in the index by 0.17 percentage point per year from December 1988 to December

    1997. All of this slowing, however, is accounted for by the replacement of the

    19821984 weights introduced in 1987 with 1986 1987 weights in 1989; subsequent

    biennial weight updates would have had virtually no net effect. Still, relying on

    out-of-date information clearly undermines the face validity of the price index, andthere are likely to be some years in which the use of updated expenditure weights

    makes a substantive difference. For both of these reasons, having more current

    expenditure weights is a change to be welcomed.

    Better Accounting for Consumer Substitution

    One long-standing criticism of the Consumer Price Index has been that it fails

    to account for changes in consumers purchases in response to changes in relative

    prices. If the price of an item a consumer is in the habit of purchasing rises, theconsumer will tend to buy relatively less of that item and relatively more of

    something else. To sustain the persons level of well-being, it should not be

    necessary to provide enough money to purchase the original consumption bundle;

    some lesser compensation should suffice. But a price index based on a fixed market

    basket simply tracks the cost of purchasing the original bundle, and thus will rise by

    more than the true increase in the consumers cost of living.

    In 1999, in an effort to move the CPI closer to its cost-of-living index objective,

    a new formula was adopted for calculating the CPI subindexes in item strata

    accounting for about two-thirds of the total index weight. Whereas the old Las-peyres formula for a price index assumed that the consumer would continue to

    purchase the same bundle as in the base period, the new geometric mean formula

    Toward a Cost-of-Living Index: Progress and Prospects 49

  • 7/29/2019 hacia un ndice del costo de vida

    6/15

    assumes instead that the share of expenditures devoted to a particular item remains

    constant. If the price of Wacky Wizmos doubles and other prices do not change, for

    example, the geometric mean formula is consistent with the expectation that

    purchases of Wacky Wizmos will fall by half. This is equivalent to assuming a unitaryelasticity of substitution among the items in any category in which the geometric

    formula is adopted. It is unlikely that the elasticity of substitution is exactly equal to

    one within any item category, but assuming a value of one almost certainly is

    preferable to assuming no substitution at all. For certain kinds of items, including

    residential rent, owners equivalent rent, utilities and professional and hospital

    medical care services, the assumption that consumers will substitute across items

    within a stratum when relative prices change seems less plausible; for these strata,

    the historical CPI formula that assumes continued consumption of the base-period

    market basket has been retained. At the time of its introduction, the BLS estimatedthat the planned adoption of the geometric mean formula for calculating the CPI

    would slow the rate of growth of the index by approximately 0.2 percentage point

    per year.4

    The absence of direct evidence about substitution among items within partic-

    ular item strata arguably makes it easier to take (approximate) corrective action: no

    available formula will be exactly right, so one makes a sensible choice and moves

    on. Correcting for substitution across item strata is, in some ways, more complex.

    Given information on current and past expenditures together with information on

    current and past prices, it is possible to infer the responsiveness of consumption to

    changes in relative prices. Diewert (1976, 1981) has shown that, when there issubstitution in response to relative price change, the true cost-of-living index can be

    approximated using any of the superlative family of price index formulas, all of

    which have in common a requirement for information on how consumption

    spending has changed over the index period. The Consumer Expenditure Survey

    provides the needed information on expenditures at the item stratum level, but

    only with a lag. Accounting for substitution across item strata in a real-time

    Consumer Price Index thus can be accomplished only in one of two ways: One

    could publish an approximate value for the substitution-corrected index and revise

    the index later, or one could publish an approximate value but not revise the index,

    even when data later become available that imply a different value.

    The widespread use of the Consumer Price Index for indexation purposes

    makes the first choice of revising the index later unattractive, at least in the eyes of

    many data users. To take a relatively recent example, the fact that the CPI is not

    revised retroactively was one of the principal reasons for its selection by the

    Department of the Treasury as the index for its inflation-protected bonds, first

    issued in January 1997. The comments received from individuals, academicians,

    investment management firms, dealers and institutional investors in response to

    4 Dalton, Greenlees and Stewart (1998) discusses the adoption of the geometric mean formula in theConsumer Price Index.

    50 Journal of Economic Perspectives

  • 7/29/2019 hacia un ndice del costo de vida

    7/15

    Treasurys 1996 Advance Notice of Proposed Rulemaking indicated a clear con-

    sensus that the selected index should be: widely recognized, published frequently,

    accurate, easily obtainable, easily understood and not revised retroactively (Federal

    Register, September 27, 1996, italics added).

    But the alternative of maintaining an index value that is at odds with the most

    recent data also seems unattractive. For now, the decision has been to leave the

    existing Consumer Price Index unchanged, but to introduce a new revisable

    indexthe Chained Consumer Price Index for All Urban Consumers, or C-CPI-U

    that is similar to the CPI except that it is constructed using a Tornqvist index

    formula, one of the superlative index number formulas designed to account for

    consumer substitution. Starting with the release of July 2002 data, preliminary

    values for the new index have been published each month along with the existing

    CPI; current index values will be subject to two rounds of revision over thesubsequent two years before becoming final.5

    Historical simulations based on data for 1990 through 1995 had suggested that

    the C-CPI-U might grow at an annual rate 0.1 to 0.2 percentage point below the

    growth rate of the CPI for All Urban Consumers (CPI-U). More recent data suggest

    a larger difference, reflecting greater variability in growth rates across CPI subin-

    dexes and correspondingly larger shifts in consumer spending in recent years. In

    2000, the only year for which final C-CPI-U data are available, the growth rate of the

    C-CPI-U was 0.8 percentage point below that of the CPI-U. Additional observations

    will be required to determine whether recent experience or the experience of theearly 1990s is more typical.

    Whatever the answer to that question, it will be interesting to see whether and

    how the new index ends up being used. For example, following the Schultze panels

    suggestion, Social Security beneficiaries could receive cost-of-living adjustments

    each year based on the preliminary values of the C-CPI-U, plus or minus an

    adjustment to reflect the difference between the final and the preliminary values of

    the two-years-earlier index (Schultze and Mackie, 2002, pp. 194 195). If a sufficient

    number of those currently using the Consumer Price Index for indexation pur-

    poses switch over to the revisable C-CPI-U, it is possible (though perhaps not likely)

    that this index eventually could replace the CPI-U.6

    5 Information regarding the new C-CPI-U can be found on the Bureau of Labor Statistics website at http://www.bls.gov/cpi/superlink.htm .6 The history of congressional decisions regarding the use of the Consumer Price Index for indexationpurposes is not especially encouraging with regard to the C-CPI-U being adopted to replace the existingCPI. There are in fact two existing CPI measures: the CPI for Urban Wage Earners and Clerical Workers(CPI-W) and the CPI for All Urban Consumers (CPI-U). Only the CPI-W existed when it was decided in1972 to index Social Security benefits to the CPI. When the more inclusive CPI-U was introduced as part

    of the 1978 CPI revision, many assumed that it would be adopted in place of the CPI-W for SocialSecurity indexation, but this has never happened, although the CPI-U typically is used for programindexation purposes legislated since 1978.

    Katharine G. Abraham 51

  • 7/29/2019 hacia un ndice del costo de vida

    8/15

    Better Accounting for Quality Change

    Better accounting for changes in the quality of the goods and services that

    consumers purchase is perhaps the greatest remaining challenge in improving the

    Consumer Price Index. In the past, quality change for the most part has been

    addressed indirectly. When a priced item disappears from an outlet and must be

    replaced, the CPI staff must decide whether the replacement item is similar enough

    to the original item that their prices can be compared. If not, the standard practice

    is to ignore the point-in-time difference in price between the replacement and the

    original item in calculating the index. In effect, this approach attributes the full

    point-in-time difference in the items prices to a difference in their quality.7 The

    standard approach to the introduction of new item samples also has been to treat

    any price differences between the items in the new and the old samples asattributable to differences in their quality.

    To account better for changes in quality, the Bureau of Labor Statistics has

    extended the use of hedonic models designed to estimate the value the market-

    place attaches to different item characteristics. Fitting a hedonic model requires

    data on the prices and characteristics of a sample of specific items. Price is

    regressed on item characteristics, and the estimated coefficients on the character-

    istics variables can be used to estimate the characteristics value in the market. Prior

    to 1998, such hedonic models were used almost exclusively for apparel items. Over

    the past few years, hedonic models have been introduced for personal computers,

    washers and dryers, microwave ovens, refrigerators, televisions, VCRs, DVD players,camcorders, consumer audio product components and college textbooks.

    It would be nice to know whether broadening the application of hedonic

    techniques beyond the appliances and boys toys to which they predominantly

    have been applied to date would change their impact. The Schultze panel suggests

    that the Bureau of Labor Statistics pursue experiments to analyze quality change

    affecting randomly selected items, increasing the probability that within-sample

    quality change biases both upward and downwardwill be identified (Schultze

    and Mackie, 2002, p. 140). The set of items for which hedonic models have been

    estimated to date largely has been determined by data availability. Constraints on

    data availability are likely to pose difficulties for the evaluation of quality change forrandomly selected items along the lines just described, though this is not to say that

    the task should not be attempted.8

    Once a hedonic model has been estimated, present practice generally calls for

    the results of the model to be used to make quality-adjusted price comparisons only

    7 See Moulton and Moses (1997) for an illuminating discussion of the historical approach to adjustingfor quality differences between replacement and disappearing items in the Consumer Price Index.8 The Schultze panels recommendation echoes a suggestion made by William Nordhaus, during a 1997meeting of the Brookings Panel on Economic Activity, that the Bureau of Labor Statistics conduct an

    audit of the Consumer Price Index, picking a random sample of items for more careful evaluation ofquality change and then using the results to estimate the overall quality bias in the CPI (Gordon andBosworth, 1997, p. 363).

    52 Journal of Economic Perspectives

  • 7/29/2019 hacia un ndice del costo de vida

    9/15

    when a replacement must be substituted for a specific item that no longer is

    available in an outlet. This means, however, that quality-adjusted price differences

    between the old and new item samples at the point of a sample rotation are not

    captured explicitly. As already noted, in the future, the BLS will be updating thesamples of items priced in particular outlets two years after the introduction of the

    original item sample for the outlet. In many cases, it should be possible to compare

    the prices of the new and the old items, and to use hedonic models to apportion

    the price difference into a quality piece and a true price change piece. Although

    one would want to proceed carefully, this approach certainly merits exploration.

    Making comparisons between the prices of items collected at different outlets, as

    often would be required when a full sample rotation is conducted, would be more

    difficult. Prices at different outlets may vary due to differences in the amenities

    associated with shopping at the different outlets, and at present there is no goodbasis for valuing such amenity differences. The Schultze panel recommends that

    research be directed toward devising such methods (Schultze and Mackie, 2002,

    pp. 176 197), a recommendation with which I concur.

    Capturing and Valuing Novel New Goods

    Perhaps the single sharpest criticism of the Consumer Price Index has been

    directed toward the unacceptably long lags that have on occasion occurred between

    the appearance of novel new goods in the marketplace and their incorporation intothe index. Items first appearing in the index long after their market debut have

    included the VCR, the home computer and the cell phone. These delays typically have

    arisen as a consequence of the item in question not fitting neatly into an existing CPI

    category and thus not being captured through routine rotations of the item sample. In

    hindsight, the propensity of the Bureau of Labor Statistics to hold off on introducing

    such items until the next scheduled item category overhaul was ill-advised. Failing to

    introduce highly visible items into the pricing structure invited easy criticism, and the

    cumulative effect of slow introductions on the index could have been significant.

    Without a doubt, however, such instances will be handled differently in the

    future, as the Bureau of Labor Statistics staff has become highly sensitized to thedesirability of bringing new goods into the index quickly. The treatment of the

    recent introduction of Viagra is a case in point. In 1999, the BLS augmented the

    prescription drug sample by adding Viagra price quotes. The weight for these

    quotes was determined based on national market share data, and the weights for

    price quotes already in the index were reduced commensurately. The motivation

    for this decision was in part to avoid the sort of criticism directed toward the long

    lags in introducing VCRs, home computers and cell phones; if asked whether

    Viagra was represented in the index, all involved wanted to be able to answer yes.

    Although that objective was realized, none of those involved was entirely comfort-able with the ad hoc way in which it was accomplished. For the future, it would be

    desirable to develop clearer guidelines for deciding when a new product is impor-

    Toward a Cost-of-Living Index: Progress and Prospects 53

  • 7/29/2019 hacia un ndice del costo de vida

    10/15

    tant enough that there should be an intervention to bring it into the index. Once

    that decision has been made, a reasonable approach might be to broaden the

    boundaries of an existing item category to encompass the new product, if necessary,

    and then to reselect the item sample for that category to give the new product theopportunity of being picked for pricing.

    A suggestion that has emerged from the outside groups asked to review the

    Consumer Price Index in recent years has been that the Bureau of Labor Statistics

    arrange for regular consultations with panels of experts . . . persons who are likely to

    know when important new consumer products have recently or soon will reach the

    market (Conference Board, 1999, p. 25, cited approvingly in Schultze and Mackie,

    2002, p. 167). Although it is hard to argue against receptivity to outside advice, this

    particular recommendation seems to me to be based on a misdiagnosis of why the BLS

    did not introduce new products as quickly as now seems desirable. The CPI staffincludes a group of commodity analysts who are charged with monitoring develop-

    ments in the product areas for which they are responsible. I am confident that these

    individuals were well aware of the growing sales of VCRs, home computers and cell

    phones from a very early stage. These items were not introduced into the CPI more

    quickly because of adherence to an overly rigid process, not because of a lack of

    information about product market developments. Managing an outside advisory group

    would consume a considerable amount of staff time and energy, and my judgment is

    that, in this case, that time and energy could be more productively devoted elsewhere.

    While there is near universal agreement that new goods should enter the Con-

    sumer Price Index relatively quickly, there is disagreement, even among those who takethe position that the cost-of-living index should be the measurement objective for the

    CPI, about whether the Bureau of Labor Statistics should attempt to incorporate into

    the index the value to consumers of newly available goods. Especially when new goods

    are not simply substitutes for existing products, they may generate substantial con-

    sumer surplus. As a result, the consumer may be able to attain any given level of utility

    with a lower income than would otherwise have been the case. Hausman (1997, 1999)

    has developed techniques for estimating the magnitude of the consumer surplus

    associated with new goods that involve estimating the virtual price that would set the

    (compensated) demand for the new good to zero. While the Schultze panels conclu-

    sion thatvirtual price reductions associated with the introduction of new goods shouldnot be imputed for use in the CPI (Schultze and Mackie, 2002, p. 160) may be too

    categorical in its rejection of these methods, I would certainly concur that adopting

    these methods any time soon would be a serious mistake.

    In part, I am concerned that the complexity of these new methods would make

    them difficult to explain to the public. Although it undoubtedly is true that there

    is much about the methods used currently to construct the CPI that the public does

    not understand, any proposed change nonetheless would require a clear explana-

    tion. The continuing professional debate over Hausmans techniques also stands in

    the way of their adoption. Hausmans methods require strong assumptions aboutthe shape of the demand curve and the nature of shocks to demand. Further,

    different assumptions can lead to very different conclusions regarding the con-

    54 Journal of Economic Perspectives

  • 7/29/2019 hacia un ndice del costo de vida

    11/15

    sumer surplus associated with new products (for example, Bresnahan, 1997). As a

    general matter, adopting cutting-edge techniques without allowing time for a

    coalescence of professional views about whether and how they should be used

    would create a real risk of undermining public trust in the CPI. I am not confidentthat professional opinion ever will coalesce around techniques for valuing the

    consumer surplus associated with new goods, given their heavy reliance on assump-

    tion as opposed to observation, but it clearly has not done so at this point.9

    In addition to the question of whether one might wish to adopt Hausman s

    methods in the construction of the CPI, there are serious questions about whether

    this would be feasible. Practical concerns include obtaining the necessary data, the

    workload associated with extending Hausmans illustrative efforts into production

    mode, and the necessity for continuing index revisions that after-the-fact calcula-

    tions of consumer surplus could require. None of this, of course, is an argumentagainst actively pursuing research in this area. It is, however, an argument against

    folding adjustments for the value of new products into the calculation of the official

    CPI, at least given the present state of knowledge.

    Should the Data Collection Process Be Rethought?

    Perhaps the most frequently suggested change in the data used to construct

    the CPI has been to substitute electronic scanner data generated at the checkout

    register for data collected byfield economists. Scanner data include information onboth quantities and prices, so that their use also holds out the promise of improved

    accounting for consumer substitution. Exploiting the considerable potential of

    such data, however, will be far more difficult than most observers had initially

    appreciated. Scanner data generally do not represent the full set of items pur-

    chased by consumers, so that even if scanner data were widely employed in index

    construction, they likely still would need to be augmented with data collected by

    BLS field economists. Properly weighting data derived from multiple sources and

    ensuring complete but nonoverlapping coverage of purchases from the full range

    of outlets could be difficult. Furthermore, scanner data are collected for purposes

    other than meeting CPI needs. Scanner data codes change frequently, and the BLScould be hard-pressed to keep up with these changes. Quality adjustment could be

    more difficult if the index were being calculated using scanner data, as there would

    be no field economist who could also provide the necessary information on product

    characteristics. Given that scanner data are collected by private firms who seek to

    make a profit from their sale, it seems unlikely that using scanner data would

    reduce the costs of index construction. It could be risky to rely on data that a private

    vendor collects mainly to serve other clients as a critical input to a major economic

    9Although the specific issues are different, the Schultze panel and others have made similar argumentsfor caution in incorporating hedonic techniques more widely into the CPI. For an interesting discussionof the political economy of statistical measurement in this context, see Hulten (2002).

    Katharine G. Abraham 55

  • 7/29/2019 hacia un ndice del costo de vida

    12/15

    indicator, although means could perhaps be devised to address this last concern.10

    At least for the short run, my sense is that the BLS should set modest goals for its

    work with scanner data, focusing on learning whether and how index calculations

    based on scanner data might differ from those using traditional CPI data.Some have expressed concern about the Consumer Expenditure Survey data

    that provide the CPI expenditure weights (Schultze and Mackie, 2002, pp. 253256;

    Branch, 1994; Lebow and Rudd, 2001, pp. 9 13). The primary basis for this

    concern is that the expenditure share weights derived from Consumer Expenditure

    Survey seem inconsistent with the Personal Consumption Expenditure estimates

    that are produced by the Bureau of Economic Analysis.

    One possible source of problems is the enormous amount of information

    requested from Consumer Expenditure Survey respondents. The survey includes

    both an interview and a personal diary component. The interview instrument,printed on 11 17 inch paper, is 143 pages long, and the diary instrument, printed

    in the same format, is 67 pages long.11 In each case, respondents are asked to

    answer hundreds of questions. It would not be surprising if respondents who knew

    that reporting a purchase would lead to further questions chose to leave some out.

    Recall also may be a problem. Very large purchases (like car purchases) and

    regularly recurring outlays such as monthly rent or utility payments likely are easier

    to report with reasonable accuracy than are smaller and/or less regular expendi-

    tures, particularly in cases where purchases have been made by more than one

    member of a household. In addition, certain socially undesirable expenditures like

    tobacco or alcohol purchases may be systematically underreported.Finding ways to reduce the respondent burden associated with the Consumer

    Expenditure Survey has become a high priority for the Bureau of Labor Statistics.

    One strategy for obtaining better data might be to divide the survey questionnaire

    into parts, so that each household would be asked only for details about certain

    categories of expenditure. Investigating whether such a change could increase

    reporting accuracy seems worthwhile, though the research value of having com-

    plete household-level expenditure data for a representative sample of households

    suggests thinking hard about whether there is a way to produce useful estimates of

    households spending in broader categories without collecting all of the underlying

    detail.Exploring the use of Personal Consumption Expenditure estimates in the

    construction of Consumer Price Index weights, as suggested by the Schultze panel

    (Schultze and Mackie, 2002, p. 274), also seems worthwhile. It should be noted,

    however, that the Personal Consumption Expenditure estimates have their own

    problems. They are derived principally from business surveys and censuses that ask

    10 Greenlees (forthcoming) discusses challenges to the incorporation of scanner data into indexconstruction, including some of those I have mentioned.11 Those who have never done so may find it illuminating to look at the Consumer ExpenditureSurvey interview and diary instruments, available on the Bureau of Labor Statistics website at http://

    www.bls.gov/cex/home.htm#forms .

    56 Journal of Economic Perspectives

  • 7/29/2019 hacia un ndice del costo de vida

    13/15

    about sales of different products and services. The nature of the underlying source

    data makes it difficult for the Bureau of Economic Analysis to disentangle fully

    business and household expenditures. Still, the Personal Consumption Expendi-

    ture estimates may be more reliable for certain kinds of household expendituresfor example, spending on alcohol and tobaccoso that some sort of hybrid

    approach to the construction of CPI weights may merit study.

    Conclusion

    The Consumer Price Index is a work in progress. Although the initiative for

    many if not most future improvements will come from the professional staff of the

    Bureau of Labor Statistics, it is very much to be hoped that the heightened interestin price measurement issues so apparent in the academic community will translate

    into research that also will be helpful. Although producing a true cost-of-living

    index may be impossible, that concept remains the polestar offering direction to

    our efforts to improve the Consumer Price Index.

    y I am grateful to Kenneth Dalton, John Greenlees, Alan Krueger, Charles Schultze, Timothy

    Taylor and Michael Waldman for helpful comments on an earlier draft of this paper.

    References

    Branch, E. Raphael. 1994. The ConsumerExpenditure Survey: A Comparative Analysis.Monthly Labor Review. December, 117:12, pp. 4755.

    Bresnahan, Timothy. 1997. Comment, inThe Economics of New Goods. T. F. Bresnahan andR. J. Gordon, eds. Chicago: University of Chi-

    cago Press, pp. 237 47.Conference Board. 1999. Measuring Prices in aDynamic Economy: Re-Examining the CPI. NewYork: Conference Board.

    Dalton, Kenneth V., John S. Greenlees and

    Kenneth J. Stewart. 1998. Incorporating a Geo-metric Mean Formula into the CPI. MonthlyLabor Review. October, 121:10, pp. 37.

    Diewert, W. Erwin. 1976. Exact and Superla-tive Index Numbers. Journal of Econometrics. May,4, pp. 115 45.

    Diewert, W. Erwin. 1981. The Economic The-ory of Index Numbers: A Survey, in Essays on

    Theory and Measurement of Consumer Behavior inHonor of Sir Richard Stone. A. Deaton, ed. Cam-bridge: Cambridge University Press, pp. 163208.

    Gordon, Robert J. and Barry P. Bosworth.

    1997. Addressing the Quality Change Issue inthe Consumer Price Index. Comments and Dis-cussion. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity. 1,pp. 350 66.

    Greenlees, John S. 2001. The U.S. CPI and

    the Cost-of-Living Objective. Paper preparedfor the Joint ECE/ILO Meeting on ConsumerPrice Indices, Geneva, November 12.

    Greenlees, John S. 2003. Round Table Re-marks: Scanner Data in Official Statistics, in Scan-ner Data and Price Indexes. R. Feenstra and M. Sha-piro, eds. Chicago: University of Chicago Press,pp. 11316.

    Hausman, Jerry. 1997. Valuation of NewGoods Under Perfect and Imperfect Competi-tion, in The Economics of New Goods. T. F. Bresna-han and R. J. Gordon, eds. Chicago: Universityof Chicago Press, pp. 209 37.

    Hausman, Jerry. 1999. Cellular Telephone,New Products and the CPI. Journal of Businessand Economic Statistics. April, 17:2, pp. 188 94.

    Toward a Cost-of-Living Index: Progress and Prospects 57

  • 7/29/2019 hacia un ndice del costo de vida

    14/15

    Hill, Peter. 1999. COL Indexes and InflationIndexes. Paper prepared for the Fifth Meetingof the International Working Group on PriceIndices, Reykjavik, Iceland, August 2527.

    Hulten, Charles R. 2002. Price Hedonics: ACritical Review. Paper prepared for the FederalReserve Bank of New York Conference on Eco-nomic Statistics, July 11.

    Lane, Walter. 2001. Addressing the NewGoods Problem in the Consumer Price Index.Paper prepared for the Sixth Meeting of theInternational Working Group on Price Indices,Canberra, Australia, April 2 6.

    Lebow, David E. and Jeremy B. Rudd. 2001.Measurement Error in the Consumer Price In-dex: Where Do We Stand? Federal Reserve

    Board Working Paper, December 7.

    Moulton, Brent R. and Karin E. Moses. 1997.

    Addressing the Quality Change Issue in the

    Consumer Price Index. Brookings Papers on Eco-

    nomic Activity. 1, pp. 305 49.

    Schultze, Charles L. and Christopher Mackie,

    eds. 2002. At What Price? Conceptualizing and Mea-

    suring Cost-of-Living and Price Indexes. Washing-

    ton, D.C.: National Academy Press.

    Triplett, Jack. 2001. Should the Cost-of-

    Living Index Provide the Conceptual Frame-

    work for a Consumer Price Index? Economic

    Journal. June, 111, pp. F311F334.

    Turvey, Ralph. 1999. True Cost of Living In-

    dexes. Paper prepared for the Fifth Meeting of

    the International Working Group on Price Indi-

    ces, Reykjavik, Iceland, August 2527.

    58 Journal of Economic Perspectives

  • 7/29/2019 hacia un ndice del costo de vida

    15/15

    This article has been cited by:

    1. M. M. G. Fase. 2007. Notes and Communications. De Economist155:2, 221-238. [CrossRef]

    2. Erling Red Larsen. 2007. Does the CPI Mirror the Cost of Living? Engel's Law Suggests Not inNorway. Scandinavian Journal of Economics109:1, 177-195. [CrossRef]

    3. Giancarlo Marini, Alessandro Piergallini, Pasquale Scaramozzino. 2007. Inflation bias after the Euro:evidence from the UK and Italy.Applied Economics39:4, 461-470. [CrossRef]

    4. Richard Vedder. 2005. Reviewing the reviewer: Ehrenberg on going broke by degree.Journal of LaborResearch26:4, 753-757. [CrossRef]

    5. Katharine G. Abraham. 2005. Distinguished Lecture on Economics in Government: What We Don'tKnow Could Hurt Us: Some Reflections on the Measurement of Economic Activity. Journal ofEconomic Perspectives19:3, 3-18. [Abstract] [View PDF article] [PDF with links]

    6. Harry J. Holzer, Paul Offner, Elaine Sorensen. 2005. What explains the continuing decline in laborforce activity among young black men? 1. Labor History46:1, 37-55. [CrossRef]

    7. Martin Gaynor, James B. Rebitzer, Lowell J. Taylor. 2004. Physician Incentives in Health MaintenanceOrganizations.Journal of Political Economy112:4, 915-931. [CrossRef]

    http://dx.doi.org/10.1086/421172http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/0023656042000329864http://pubs.aeaweb.org/doi/pdfplus/10.1257/089533005774357833http://pubs.aeaweb.org/doi/pdf/10.1257/089533005774357833http://dx.doi.org/10.1257/089533005774357833http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/s12122-005-1010-8http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/00036840500438962http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-9442.2007.00487.xhttp://dx.doi.org/10.1007/s10645-007-9056-z